Exogenous growth model

Exogenous growth model

The Exogenous growth model, also known as the Neo-classical growth model or Solow growth model is a term used to sum up the contributions of various authors to a model of long-run economic growth within the framework of neoclassical economics.

Development of the model

The Neo-classical model was an extension to the 1946 Harrod-Domar model that included a new term, productivity growth. The most important contribution was probably the work done by Robert Solow; [cite journal |last=Solow |first=Robert M. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1956 |month= |title=A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth |journal=Quarterly Journal of Economics |volume=70 |issue=1 |pages=65–94 |doi= |url=http://www.jstor.org/pss/1884513 |accessdate= |quote= ] in 1956, Solow and T.W. Swan developed a relatively simple growth model which fit available data on US economic growth with some success. [cite journal |last=Solow |first=Robert M. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1957 |month= |title=Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function |journal=Review of Economics and Statistics |volume=3 |issue=3 |pages=312–320 |doi= |url=http://www.jstor.org/pss/1926047 |accessdate= |quote= ] Solow received the 1987 Nobel Prize in Economics for his work on the model.

Solow also was the first to develop a growth model with different vintages of capital.Haines, Joel D. (January 1, 2006) Competitiveness Review " [http://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-151274670.html A framework for managing the sophistication of the components of technology for global competition.] " Volume 16; Issue 2; Page 106.] The idea behind Solow's vintage capital growth model is that new capital is more valuable than old (vintage) capital because capital is produced based on known technology and because technology is improving. Both Paul Romer and Robert Lucas, Jr. subsequently developed alternatives to Solow's neo-classical growth model. Today, economists use Solow's sources-of-growth accounting to estimate the separate effects on economic growth of technological change, capital, and labor.

Extension to the Harrod-Domar model

Solow extended the Harrod-Domar model by:
* Adding labor as a factor of production;
* Requiring diminishing returns to labor and capital separately, and constant returns to scale for both factors combined;
* Introducing a time-varying technology variable distinct from capital and labor.The capital-output and capital-labor ratios are not fixed as they are in the Harrod-Domar model. These refinements allow increasing capital intensity to be distinguished from technological progress.

hort run implications

* Policy measures like tax cuts or investment subsidies can affect the steady state level of "output" but not the long-run growth rate.
* Growth is affected only in the short-run as the economy converges to the new steady state output level.
* The rate of growth as the economy converges to the steady state is determined by the rate of capital accumulation.
* Capital accumulation is in turn determined by the savings rate (the proportion of output used to create more capital rather than being consumed) and the rate of capital depreciation.

Long run implications

In neoclassical growth models, the long-run rate of growth is Exogenously determined - in other words, it is determined outside of the model. A common prediction of these models is that an economy will always converge towards a steady state rate of growth, which depends only on the rate of technological progress and the rate of labor force growth.

A country with a higher saving rate will experience faster growth, e.g. Singapore had a 40% saving rate in the period 1960 to 1996 and annual GDP growth of 5-6%, compared with Kenya in the same time period which had a 15% saving rate and annual GDP growth of just 1%. This relationship was anticipated in the earlier models, and is retained in the Solow model; however, in the very long-run capital accumulation appears to be less significant than technological innovation in the Solow model.

Assumptions

The key assumption of the neoclassical growth model is that capital is subject to diminishing returns. Given a fixed stock of labor, the impact on output of the last unit of capital accumulated will always be less than the one before. Assuming for simplicity no technological progress or labor force growth, diminishing returns implies that at some point the amount of new capital produced is only just enough to make up for the amount of existing capital lost due to depreciationref|depreciation. At this point, because of the assumptions of no technological progress or labor force growth, the economy ceases to grow.

Assuming non-zero rates of labor growth complicates matters somewhat, but the basic logic still appliesref|SteadStateWhen - in the short-run the rate of growth slows as diminishing returns take effect and the economy converges to a constant "steady-state" rate of growth (that is, "no" economic growth per-capita).

Including non-zero technological progress is very similar to the assumption of non-zero workforce growth, in terms of "effective labor": a new steady state is reached with constant output per "worker-hour required for a unit of output". However, in this case, per-capita output is growing at the rate of technological progress in the "steady-state"ref|MacroEconomics248 (that is, the rate of productivity growth).

Variations in productivity's effects

Within the Solow growth model, the Solow residual or total factor productivity is an often used measure of technological progress. The model can be reformulated in slightly different ways using different productivity assumptions, or different measurement metrics:
* Average Labor Productivity (ALP) is economic output per labor hour.
*Multifactor productivity (MFP) is output divided by a weighted average of capital and labor inputs. The weights used are usually based on the aggregate input shares either factor earns. This ratio is often quoted as: 33% return to capital and 66% return to labor (in Western nations), but Robert J. Gordon says the weight to labor is more commonly assumed to be 75%ref|RJG.

In a growing economy, capital is accumulated faster than people are born, so the denominator in the growth function under the MFP calculation is growing faster than in the ALP calculation. Hence, MFP growth is almost always lower than ALP growth. (Therefore, measuring in ALP terms increases the apparent capital deepening effect.)

Technically, MFP is measured by the "Solow residual", not ALP..

Empirical evidence

A key prediction of neoclassical growth models is that the income levels of poor countries will tend to catch up with or converge towards the income levels of rich countries. Since the 1950s, the opposite empirical result has been observed "on average". If the average growth rate of countries since, say, 1960 is plotted against initial GDP per capita (i.e. GDP per capita in 1960), one observes a positive relationship. In other words, the developed world appears to have grown at a faster rate than the developing world, the opposite of what is expected according to a prediction of convergence.Fact|date=September 2007 However, a few formerly poor countries, notably Japan, do appear to have converged with rich countries, and in the case of Japan actually exceeded other countries' productivity, some theorise that this is what has caused Japan's poor growth recently - "convergent growth rates are still expected, even after convergence has occurred"; leading to over-optimistic investment, and actual recession.

The evidence is stronger for convergence within countries. For instance the per-capita income levels of the southern states of the United States have tended to converge to the levels in the Northern states. These observations have led to the adoption of the conditional convergence concept. Whether convergence occurs or not depends on the characteristics of the country or region in question, such as:
* Institutional arrangements
* Free markets internally, and trade policy with other countries.
* Education policy

Evidence for conditional convergence comes from multivariate, cross-country regressions.

If productivity were associated with high technology then the introduction of information technology should have led to a noticeable productivity acceleration over the past twenty years; but it has not: "see": Solow computer paradox.

Econometric analysis on Singapore and the other "East Asian Tigers" has produced the surprising result that although output per worker has been rising, almost none of their rapid growth had been due to rising per-capita productivity (they have a low "Solow residual")ref|Alwyn.

Criticisms of the model

Empirical evidence offers mixed support for the model. Limitations of the model include its failure to take account of entrepreneurship (which may be catalyst behind economic growth) and strength of institutions (which facilitate economic growth). In addition, it does not explain how or why technological progress occurs. This failing has led to the development of endogenous growth theory, which endogenizes technological progress and/or knowledge accumulation.

Some critics suggest that Schumpeter’s 1939 Theory of Business Cycles, modern Institutionalism and Austrian economics offer an even better prospect of explaining how long run economic growth occur than the later Lucas/Romer models.

Marxist critics of growth theory itself have questioned the model's underlying assertion that economic growth is necessarily a good thing.ref|dieOff Furthermore, the use of a representative agent hides equity issues.

Graphical representation of the model

The model starts with a neoclassical production function Y/L = F(K/L), rearranged to y = f(k), which is the orange curve on the graph. From the production function; output per worker is a function of capital per worker. The production function assumes diminishing returns to capital in this model, as denoted by the slope of the production function.

n = population growth rate
d = depreciation
k = capital per worker
y = output/income per worker
L = labor force
s = saving rate

Capital per worker change is determined by three variables:
*Investment (saving) per worker
*Population growth, increasing population decreases the level of capital per worker.
*Depreciation - capital stock declines as it depreciates.

When sy > (n+d)k, in other words, when the savings rate is greater than the population growth rate plus the depreciation rate, when the green line is above the black line on the graph, then capital (k) per worker is increasing, this is known as capital deepening. Where capital is increasing at a rate only enough to keep pace with population increase and depreciation it is known as capital widening.

The curves intersect at point A, the "steady state". At the steady state, output per worker is constant. However total output is growing at the rate of n, the rate of population growth.

Left of point A, point k1 for example, the saving per worker is greater than the amount needed to maintain a steady level of capital, so capital per worker increases. There is capital deepening from y1 to y0, and thus output per worker increases.

Right of point A where sy < (n+d)k, point y2 for example, capital per worker is falling, as investment is not enough to combat population growth and depreciation. Therefore output per worker falls from y2 to y0.

The model and changes in the saving rate

The graph is very similar to the above, however, it now has a second savings function s1y, the blue curve. It demonstrates that an increase in the saving rate shifts the function up. Saving per worker is now greater than population growth plus depreciation, so capital accumulation increases, shifting the steady state from point A to B. As can be seen on the graph, output per worker correspondingly moves from y0 to y1. Initially the economy expands faster, but eventually goes back to the steady state rate of growth which equals n.

There is now permanently higher capital and productivity per worker, but economic growth is the same as before the savings increase.

The model and changes in population

This graph is again very similar to the first one, however, the population growth rate has now increased from n to n1, this introduces a new capital widening line (n1+d)

Mathematical framework

The Solow growth model can be described by the interaction of five basic macroeconomic equations:
* Macro-production function
* GDP equation
* Savings function
* Change in capital
* Change in workforce

Macro-production function

Y=AK^aL^{1-a},

This is a Cobb-Douglas function where Y represents the total production in an economy. A represents multifactor productivity (often generalized as technology), K is capital and L is labor.

An important relation in the macro-production function:

Y=AK^aL^{1-a} leftrightarrow y=Ak^a

Which is the macro-production function divided by L to give total production per capita y and the capital intensity k

GDP equation

Y=C+G+I+NX,

Where C is private consumption, G is public consumption, "NX" is net exports, and I represents investments, or savings. Note that in the Solow model, we represent public consumption and private consumption simply as total consumption from both the public and government sector. Also notice that net exports and government spending are excluded from Solow's model. This equation is called the GDP equation because it is calculated much the same way as is the Gross domestic product (or more precisely the Gross national product).

avings function

I=sY,

This function depicts savings, I as a portion s of the total production Y.

Change in capital

Delta K=sY-,delta K,

The delta, is the rate of depreciation.

Change in workforce

L_{t+1}=L_t(1+gL),

gL is the growth function for L.

The model's solution

First we'll need to define some growth functions.

1. Growth in capital gK=frac{Delta K}{K}

2. Growth in the GDP gY=frac{Delta Y}{Y}

3. Growth function for capital intensity gk=gK-gL,

Solution assuming no multifactor productivity growth

This simplification makes the solution's derivation more comprehensible, as it allows the following calculations:

gK=frac{Delta K}{K} ightarrowfrac{sY-dK}{K} ightarrowfrac{sY}{K}-d

When there is no growth in A then we can assume the following based on the first calculation:

gK=gL=gY,

Moving on:

gK=frac{sY}{K}-d Divide the fraction by L and you will see that gK=frac{sy}{k}-d

gK=frac{sy}{k}-d ightarrowfrac{sAk^a}{k}-d ightarrowfrac{sA}{k^{1-a-d

By subtracting gL from gK we end up with:

gk=frac{sA}{k^{1-a-(d+gL)

If k is known in the year t then this formula can be used to calculate k in any given year.

In the first segment on the right side of the equation we see that lim_{k o 0} gk=infty and lim_{k o infty}gk=-(d+gL)

Deriving the Steady-state equation:

frac{dfrac{K}{L{dt}=frac{dk}{dt}, where k=K/L and k denotes capital per worker.

Differentiating we obtain:

frac{dk}{dt}=frac{frac{dk}{dt}L-frac{dL}{dt}K}{L^2}which is

frac{dk}{dt}=frac{frac{dK}{dt{L}-left(frac{frac{dL}{dt{L}frac{K}{L} ight)we know that

frac{frac{dL}{dt{L} is the population growth rate over time denoted by n.

Furthermore we know that

frac{dK}{dt}=sY-delta K,

where delta, is the depreciation rate of capital.

Hence we obtain:

dk=sy-(n+delta )k,

which is the fundamental Solow equation. The same can be done if technological progress is included.

In the steady state the change in dk must be 0.

sy=(n+delta )k,

The steady state consumption will then be:

c=y-(n+delta )k,^*


A Simple Explanation

Consider a simple case Cobb-Douglas production function:


Y=K^{alpha}N^{1-alpha},,

where Y is level output, K level of capital, N level of employment (given, fixed), and 0 is relative capital intensity (given, fixed). Net capital accumulation per capita in period t is given by:


frac{K_{t+1{N}-frac{K_t}{N}=sleft(frac{Y_t}{N} ight)-{delta}left(frac{K_t}{N} ight),

where s is the savings rate, and {delta} the depreciation rate. The economy reaches a steady state level of output and capital when net capital accumulation per capita is zero. That is,


sleft(frac{Y}{N} ight)={delta}left(frac{K}{N} ight),

the amount of total investment (left side) is equal to the amount of capital depreciation (right side) in any given period. From the production function we know that output per capita is given by:


frac{Y}{N}=left(frac{K}{N} ight)^alpha,

which implies that the steady state levels of capital and output, denoted by asterisks, are:


frac{K^*}{N}=left(frac{s}{delta} ight)^{frac{1}{1-alpha,

and


frac{Y^*}{N}=left(frac{s}{delta} ight)^{frac{alpha}{1-alpha.

for given values of s,delta, and alpha.

Now consider output as a Cobb-Douglas function of capital and effective labor AN:


Y=K^{alpha}left(AN ight)^{1-alpha},,

where increases in technology A positively affect output Y by improving the efficiency of labor N. If technology grows at a constant positive rate of g_A, and labor at g_A, then their product AN grows at a rate approximately equal to g_A+g_N. Consequently, the steady state level of output per unit of effective labor (derived from the original steady state condition)


frac{Y^*}{AN}=left(frac{s}{delta} ight)^{frac{alpha}{1-alpha,

is actually declining since output Y is by definition growing at zero in the steady state (left side numerator), whereas (in the denominator) effective labor is growing at g_A+g_N>0. Therefore, in order to offset this additional source of per unit erosion in steady state output, the steady state condition must be modified to read:


sleft(frac{Y}{AN} ight)=left(delta+g_A+g_N ight)left(frac{K}{AN} ight)

total investment (left side) must equal the amount of growth in effective labor in addition to the amount of capital depreciation. This modification implies that the steady state level of output per unit of effective labor is


frac{Y^*}{AN}=left(frac{s}{delta+g_A+g_N} ight)^frac{alpha}{1-alpha}.

Similarly, the steady state level of capital per unit of effecitve labor is


frac{K^*}{AN}=left(frac{s}{delta+g_A+g_N} ight)^frac{1}{1-alpha}.

Note: Although per unit growth is zero, the absolute levels of output Y^* and capital K^* in the steady state are still growing at a constant positive rate g_A+g_N>0. This result is sometimes referred to as balanced growth. Also note that neither the savings rate s, the depreciation rate delta, nor the relative intensity of capital alpha affects the rate of growth of output in the steady state, although it does still contribute to the initial level of output and capital at the start of a period of balanced growth.

The golden rule savings rate s^* maximizes the steady state level of aggregate consumption C^* per unit of effective labor, as defined by the national income (GDP) identity:


frac{Y^*}{AN}=frac{C^*}{AN}+frac{I^*}{AN}.

Assuming that the steady state level of investment I^* equals sY^*, the golden rule savings rate solves the unconstrained maximization problem


max_s frac{C^*}{AN}=left(frac{s}{delta+g_A+g_N} ight)^frac{alpha}{1-alpha}-sleft(frac{s}{delta+g_A+g_N} ight)^frac{alpha}{1-alpha}.

Since


ln{left(frac{C^*}{AN} ight)}=ln{left(1-s ight)}+left(frac{alpha}{1-alpha} ight)ln{left(frac{s}{delta+g_A+g_N} ight)},

this implies


frac{partialln{left(frac{C^*}{AN} ight){partial s}=-frac{1}{1-s}+left(frac{alpha}{1-alpha} ight)left(frac{delta+g_N+g_A}{s} ight)left(frac{1}{delta+g_N+g_A} ight),

setting equal to zero and simplifying,


0=-s+(1-s)left(frac{alpha}{1-alpha} ight),

finally,


s^*=alpha,.

Note: This implies that aggregate consumption per unit of effective labor in the steady state is maximized when the savings rate is exactly equal to the relative intensity of capital in the production function.


=See also=
* Golden rule savings rate
* Growth theory - historical overview
* Endogenous growth theory
* Labor-augmenting


= References =


=External links=
* [http://www.fgn.unisg.ch/eurmacro/Tutor/solow_index.html Java applet where you can experiment with parameters and learn about Solow model]
* [http://demonstrations.wolfram.com/SolowGrowthModel/ Solow Growth Model] by Fiona Maclachlan, The Wolfram Demonstrations Project.
* [http://www.pitt.edu/~mgahagan/Solow.htm A step-by-step explanation of how to understand the Solow Model]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно решить контрольную?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Exogenous Growth — The belief that economic growth arises due to influences outside the economy or company of interest. Exogenous growth assumes that economic prosperity is primarily determined by external rather than internal factors. According to this belief,… …   Investment dictionary

  • Neoclassical growth model — See also: Ramsey growth model The neoclassical growth model, also known as the Solow–Swan growth model or exogenous growth model, is a class of economic models of long run economic growth set within the framework of neoclassical economics.… …   Wikipedia

  • Malthusian growth model — The Malthusian growth model, sometimes called the simple exponential growth model, is essentially exponential growth based on a constant rate of compound interest. The model is named after the Reverend Thomas Malthus, who authored An Essay on the …   Wikipedia

  • Endogenous growth theory — Development Economics …   Wikipedia

  • Harrod-Domar model — The Harrod Domar model is used in development economics to explain an economy s growth rate in terms of the level of saving and productivity of capital. It suggests that there is no natural reason for an economy to have balanced growth. The model …   Wikipedia

  • Balanced-growth equilibrium — In the standard exogenous growth model the type of equilibrium studied is a balanced growth equilibrium. In the balanced growth equilibrium the capital intensity of the economy its capital stockdivided by its total output is constant. However,… …   Wikipedia

  • Mathematical model — Not to be confused with the same term that is used in model theory, a branch of mathematical logic. An artifact that is used to illustrate a mathematical idea may also be called a mathematical model, the usage of which is the reverse of the sense …   Wikipedia

  • Economic growth — GDP real growth rates, 1990–1998 and 1990–2006, in selected countries …   Wikipedia

  • Unified growth theory — In economics, endogenous growth theory or new growth theory was developed in the 1980s as a response to criticism of the neo classical growth model. In the exogenous neoclassical growth model the long run rate of growth is determined by… …   Wikipedia

  • IS/LM model — The IS curve moves to the right, causing higher interest rates (i) and expansion in the real economy (real GDP, or Y). The IS/LM model (Investment Saving/Liquidity preference Money supply) is a macroeconomic tool that demonstrates the… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”