Risk dominance

Risk dominance

Infobox equilibrium
name = Risk dominance
Payoff dominance
subsetof = Nash equilibrium
supersetof =
discoverer = John Harsanyi, Reinhard Selten
usedfor = Non-cooperative games
example = Stag hunt

Risk dominance and payoff dominance are two related refinements of the Nash equilibrium (NE) solution concept in game theory, defined by John Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten. A Nash equilibrium is considered payoff dominant if it is Pareto superior to all other Nash equilibria in the game.fn|1 When faced with a choice among equilibria, all players would agree on the payoff dominant equilibrium since it offers at least as much payoff as each player's best alternative. Conversely, a Nash equilibrium is considered risk dominant if it has the largest basin of attraction, meaning the more uncertainty players have about the actions of the other player(s), the more likely they will choose the risk dominant strategy.

The payoff matrix in Figure 1 provides a simple two-player, two-strategy example of a game with two pure Nash equilibria. The strategy pair (Hunt, Hunt) is payoff dominant since payoffs are higher for both players compared to the other pure NE, (Gather, Gather). On the other hand, (Gather, Gather) risk dominates (Hunt, Hunt) since if uncertainty exists about the other player's action, gathering will provide a higher expected payoff. The game in Figure 1 is a well-known game-theoretic dilemma called stag hunt. The rationale behind it is that communal action (hunting) yields a higher return if all players combine their skills, but if it is unknown whether the other player helps in hunting, gathering might turn out to be the better individual strategy for food provision, since it does not depend on coordinating with the other player. In addition, gathering alone is preferred to gathering in competition with others. This game is similar to the Prisoner's dilemma in that it provides a rationale why collective action might fail in the absence of credible commitments.

Formal definition

The game given in Figure 2 is a coordination game if the following payoff inequalities hold for player 1 (rows): A > B, D > C, and for player 2 (columns): a > b, d > c. The strategy pairs (H, H) and (G, G) are then the only pure Nash equilibria. In addition there is a mixed Nash equilibrium where player 1 plays H with probability p = (d-c)/(a-b-c+d) and G with probability 1–p; player 2 plays H with probability q = (D-C)/(A-B-C+D) and G with probability 1–q.

Strategy pair (H, H) payoff dominates (G, G) if A ≥ D, a ≥ d, and at least one of the two is a strict inequality: A > D or a > d.

Strategy pair (G, G) risk dominates (H, H) if the product of the deviation losses is highest for (G, G) (Harsanyi and Selten, 1988, Lemma 5.4.4). In other words, if the following inequality holds: nowrap|(C – D)(c – d)≥(B – A)(b – a). If the inequality is strict then (G, G) strictly risk dominates (H, H).fn|2(That is, players have more incentive to deviate).

If the game is symmetric, so if A = a, B = b, etc., the inequality allows for a simple interpretation: We assume the players are unsure about which strategy the opponent will pick and assign probabilities for each strategy. If each player assigns probabilities ½ to H and G each, then (G, G) risk dominates (H, H) if the expected payoff from playing G exceeds the expected payoff from playing H: nowrap|½ B + ½ D ≥ ½ A + ½ C, or simply nowrap|B + D ≥ A + C.

Another way to calculate the risk dominant equilibrium is to calculate the risk factor for all equilibria and to find the equilibrium with the smallest risk factor. To calculate the risk factor in our 2x2 game, consider the expected payoff to a player if they play H: E [pi_H] =p A + (1-p) C (where "p" is the probability that the other player will play H), and compare it to the expected payoff if they play G: E [pi_G] =p B + (1-p) D. The value of "p" which makes these two expected values equal is the risk factor for the equilibrium (H, H), with 1-p the risk factor for playing (G, G). You can also calculate the risk factor for playing (G, G) by doing the same calculation, but setting "p" as the probability the other player will play G. An interpretation for "p" is it is the smallest probability that the opponent will play a strategy such that the payoff of that strategy is greater than if the other strategy was played.

Equilibrium selection

Even though rational choice theory might suggest that players converge on the payoff dominant equilibriumfn|3 a number of evolutionary approaches have established that when played in a large population, players might fail to do so and instead end up in the payoff dominated, risk dominant equilibrium. Two separate evolutionary models both support the idea that the risk dominant equilibrium is more likely to occur. The first model, based on replicator dynamics, predicts that a population is more likely to adopt the risk dominant equilibrium than the payoff dominant equilibrium. The second model, based on best response strategy revision and mutation, predicts that the risk dominant state is the only stochastically stable equilibrium. Both models assume that multiple two-player games are played in a population of N players. The players are matched randomly with opponents, with each player having equal likelihoods of drawing any of the N−1 other players. The players start with a pure strategy, G or H, and play this strategy against their opponent. In replicator dynamics, the population game is repeated in sequential generations where subpopulations change based on the success of their chosen stratregies. In best response, players update their strategies to improve expected payoffs in the subsequent generations. The recognition of Kandori, Mailath & Rob (1993) and Young (1993) was that if the rule to update one's strategy allows for mutationfn|4, and the probability of mutation vanishes, i.e. asymptotically reaches zero over time, the likelihood that the risk dominant equilibrium is reached goes to one, even if it is payoff dominated.

Notes

*fnb|1 A single Nash equilibrium is trivially payoff and risk dominant if it is the only NE in the game.
*fnb|2 Similar distinctions between strict and weak exist for most definitions here, but are not denoted explicitly unless necessary.
*fnb|3 Harsanyi and Selten (1988) propose that the payoff dominant equilibrium is the rational choice in the stag hunt game.

References

* Samuel Bowles: "Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution", Princeton University Press, pp. 45–46 (2004) ISBN 0691091633
* Drew Fudenberg and David K. Levine: "The Theory of Learning in Games", MIT Press, p. 27 (1999) ISBN 0262061945
* John C. Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten: "A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games", MIT Press (1988) ISBN 0262081733
* Michihiro Kandori, George J. Mailath & Rafael Rob: "Learning, Mutation, and Long-run Equilibria in Games", "Econometrica" 61, pp. 29–56 (1993) [http://econpapers.repec.org/article/ecmemetrp/v_3A61_3Ay_3A1993_3Ai_3A1_3Ap_3A29-56.htm Abstract]
* Roger B. Myerson: "Game Theory, Analysis of Conflict", Harvard University Press, pp. 118–119 (1991) ISBN 0674341155
* Larry Samuelson: "Evolutionary Games and Equilibrium Selection", MIT Press (1997) ISBN 026219382-5
* H. Peyton Young: "The Evolution of Conventions", "Econometrica", 61, pp. 57–84 (1993) [http://econpapers.repec.org/article/ecmemetrp/v_3a61_3ay_3a1993_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a57-84.htm Abstract]
* H. Peyton Young: "Individual Strategy and Social Structure", Princeton University Press (1998) ISBN 0691086877


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужен реферат?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Dominance (game theory) — In game theory, dominance (also called strategic dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player s opponents may play. Many simple games can be solved using dominance.The opposite,… …   Wikipedia

  • Dominance-based rough set approach — (DRSA) is an extension of rough set theory for multi criteria decision analysis (MCDA), introduced by Greco, Matarazzo and Słowiński. [1][2][3] The main change comparing to the classical rough sets is the substitution of the indiscernibility… …   Wikipedia

  • Dominance-based Rough Set Approach — (DRSA) is an extension of rough set theory for Multi Criteria Decision Analysis (MCDA), introduced by Greco, Matarazzo and Słowiński Greco, S., Matarazzo, B., Słowiński, R.: Rough sets theory for multicriteria decision analysis. European Journal… …   Wikipedia

  • Risk aversion — is a concept in psychology, economics, and finance, based on the behavior of humans (especially consumers and investors) while exposed to uncertainty. Risk aversion is the reluctance of a person to accept a bargain with an uncertain payoff rather …   Wikipedia

  • Risk Fleet Theory —    A naval strategic theory formulated by German Admiral Alfred von Tirpitz. Whereas the Tirpitz Plan was developed to challenge British naval dominance of the high seas with a formidable German battle fleet, the risk fleet theory articulated in… …   Encyclopedia of the Age of Imperialism, 1800–1914

  • Risk economy — In economics, the term risk economy refers to the nature of an economy as based in risk, rather than in security. Translated, it refers to the nature of a (typically Capitalist) economy that has limited established economic protectionism or… …   Wikipedia

  • Strategic dominance — For the business strategy, see Dominance (economics). In game theory, strategic dominance (commonly called simply dominance) occurs when one strategy is better than another strategy for one player, no matter how that player s opponents may play.… …   Wikipedia

  • Stochastic dominance — is a form of stochastic ordering. The term is used in decision theory to refer to situations where one lottery (a probability distribution over outcomes) can be ranked as superior to another. It is based on preferences regarding outcomes (e.g.,… …   Wikipedia

  • Marginal conditional stochastic dominance — In finance, marginal conditional stochastic dominance is a condition under which a portfolio can be improved in the eyes of all risk averse investors by incrementally moving funds out of one asset (or one sub group of the portfolio s assets) and… …   Wikipedia

  • Bondage & Discipline, Dominance & Submission, Sadism & Masochism — Das Halsband ist neben dem Ring der O ein gebräuchliches Symbol des BDSM. BDSM ist die heute in der Fachliteratur gebräuchliche Sammelbezeichnung für eine Gruppe miteinander verwandter sexueller Vorlieben, die oft ungenauer als Sadomasochismus… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”