Risk compensation

Risk compensation

In ethology, risk compensation is an effect whereby individual people may tend to adjust their behavior in response to perceived changes in risk. It is seen as self-evident that individuals will tend to behave in a more cautious manner if their perception of risk or danger increases. Another way of stating this is that individuals will behave less cautiously in situations where they feel "safer" or more protected.

Contents

Description

There is evidence that suggests that such an effect is seen in humans, associated with the use of safety features such as car seat belts and climbing rope. The evidence is particularly compelling for the case of antilock braking systems. The existence of this balancing behaviour does not mean an intervention does not work; the effect could be less than, equal to, or even more than the true efficacy of the intervention, depending on how well the perceived efficacy matches actual efficacy - and this will differ from individual to individual. It is likely to be least when an intervention is imperceptible and greatest when an intervention is intrusive or conspicuous.

The theory grew largely out of investigations of road safety interventions. It was noted that some interventions had failed to achieve the forecast savings in lives and injuries (e.g. Adams' discussion of seatbelt legislation). Theorists speculated that while the studies demonstrated that the probability of injury given a crash had reduced, the fact that the overall probability of injury was unchanged indicated that there must have been some change in the probability of crashing.

Related research

Anti-lock brakes

There are at least three studies which show that drivers' response to antilock brakes is to drive faster, follow closer and brake later, accounting for the failure of ABS to result in any measurable improvement in road safety. The studies were performed in Canada, Denmark and Germany.[1] [2] [3]

A study led by Fred Mannering, a professor of civil engineering at Purdue University supports risk compensation, terming it the "offset hypothesis".[4]

Bicycle helmets

A study published in the March 2007 issue of Accident Analysis & Prevention stated that drivers drove an average of 8.5 cm closer, and came within 1 meter 23% more often, when a cyclist was wearing a helmet.[5] Statements made in the report included: “The closer a driver is to the cyclist, the greater chance of a collision.”, “Drivers passed closer to the rider the further out into the road he was.”, “The bicyclist’s apparel affects the amount of clearance the overtaking motorist gives the bicyclist”. This research thus implies risk compensation, not among cyclists but among fellow road users. The issue of risk compensation among cyclists has been a central topic in the quite heated debate concerning effectiveness of helmet legislation.

Ski helmets

“There is no evidence they reduce fatalities,” said Dr. Jasper Shealy, a professor from Rochester Institute of Technology who has been studying skiing and snowboarding injuries for more than 30 years. “We are up to 40 percent usage but there has been no change in fatalities in a 10-year period.”[6][7] There is evidence that helmeted skiers tend to go faster.[8]

Seat belts

In 1981 John Adams published a paper, The efficacy of seatbelt legislation: A comparative study of road accident fatality statistics from 18 countries, Dept of Geography University College, London 1981 - published in 1982 by the Society of Automotive Engineers.[2] This showed that in the countries studied, which included states with and without seat belt laws, there was no correlation between the passing of seat belt legislation and the total reductions in injuries or fatalities. When all associated fatalities and injuries in road accidents were included, it appeared that some accidents were being displaced from car drivers to pedestrians and other road users.

This paper was published at a time when Britain was considering a seat belt law, so the Department of Transport commissioned a report into the issue. In the event the report's author, Isles, agreed with Adams' conclusions. The Isles Report was never published officially but a copy was leaked to the Press some years later.[9] The law was duly passed and subsequent investigation showed some reduction in fatalities, the cause of which could not be conclusively stated, due to the simultaneous introduction of evidential breath testing.[10]

Other research has taken groups of drivers, including those who did and did not habitually wear seat-belts, and measured the effect on driving style in the habitually unbelted. The drivers were found to drive faster and less carefully when belted.[11] However, a 2007 study used data available for the years 1985-2002 from the US' National Highway Traffic Safety Administration’s (2005) Fatal Accident Reporting System (FARS). This study included fatalities of all road accident victims, including car occupants, and measured them using a fixed-effects model. It concluded that between 1985 and 2002 there were "significant reductions in fatality rates for occupants and motorcyclists after the implementation of belt use laws", and that "seatbelt use rate is significantly related to lower fatality rates for the total, pedestrian, and all nonoccupant models even when controlling for the presence of other state traffic safety policies and a variety of demographic factors."[12]

Skydiving

Booth's rule #2, coined by skydiving pioneer Bill Booth, states that "The safer skydiving gear becomes, the more chances skydivers will take, in order to keep the fatality rate constant". Even though skydiving equipment has made huge leaps forward in terms of reliability in the past two decades, and safety devices such as AADs have been introduced, the fatality rate has stayed roughly constant since the early 1980s.[3] This can largely be attributed to an increase in the popularity of high performance canopies, which fly much faster than traditional parachutes. High speed manoeuvres close to the ground have increased the number of landing fatalities in recent years,[4] even though these jumpers have perfectly functioning parachutes over their heads.

Speed limits

A 1994 study by Jeremy Jackson and Roger Blackman,[13] using a driving simulator, showed that although increased speed limits and reduced speeding fines significantly increased driving speed, there was no effect on accident frequency. It also showed that increased accident cost caused large and significant reductions in accident frequency but no change in speed choice. The abstract states that the results suggest that regulation of specific risky behaviors such as speed choice may have little influence on accident rates.

Safety equipment in children

Experimental studies have suggested that children who wear protective equipment are likely to take more risks.[14]

Use of condoms in AIDS prevention

Harvard researcher Edward C. Green argued that the risk compensation phenomenon could explain the failure of condom distribution programs to reverse HIV prevalence. Dr Green says his ideas are motivated by empirical research, rather than by any moral or religious association with the Catholic Church. Green provided more detailed explanations of his views in an op-ed article for The Washington Post[15] and an extended interview with the BBC.[16] This view is shared by other specialists.[17]

Risk homeostasis

An associated theory is known as risk homeostasis. This extends risk compensation theory somewhat, although in practice the two terms are often used interchangeably.

Professor Gerald J. S. Wilde illustrates this by reference to the Swedish experience when they changed from left- to right-hand drive in 1967.[5] This was followed by a marked reduction in the traffic fatality rate, but the trend returned to its previous values after about 18 months. Drivers had responded to increased perceived danger by taking more care; as they became accustomed to the new regime, the additional care evaporated.

Risk compensation is now widely accepted, but risk homeostasis, which goes much further, has a much smaller following.

See also

References

  1. ^ Grant and Smiley, "Driver response to antilock brakes: a demonstration on behavioural adaptation" from Proceedings, Canadian Multidisciplinary Road Safety Conference VIII, June 14–16, Saskatchewan 1993.
  2. ^ Sagberg, Fosser, and Saetermo, "An investigation of behavioural adaptation to airbags and antilock brakes among taxi drivers" Accident Analysis and Prevention #29 pp 293-302 1997.
  3. ^ Aschenbrenner and Biehl, "Improved safety through improved technical measures? empirical studies regarding risk compensation processes in relation to anti-lock braking systems". In Trimpop and Wilde, Challenges to Accident Prevention: The issue of risk compensation behaviour (Groningen, NL, Styx Publications, 1994).
  4. ^ Venere, Emil. (2006-09-27). Study: Airbags, antilock brakes not likely to reduce accidents, injuries. Purdue University News Service.
  5. ^ Strange but True: Helmets Attract Cars to Cyclists: Scientific American
  6. ^ http://www.rit.edu/news/utilities/pdf/2008/2008_03_04_Buffalo_News_use_head_on_slopes_Shealy.pdf Use your head on the ski slopes. Don’t just rely on your helmet. By Fletcher Doyle --News Sports Reporter. Buffalo News. Updated: 03/04/08 9:19 AM.
  7. ^ Do Helmets Reduce Fatalities or Merely Alter the Patterns of Death? Journal of ASTM International Volume 5, Issue 10 (November 2008). ISSN: 1546-962X. Shealy, Jasper E. Professor Emeritus, Rochester Institute of Technology, NY. Johnson, Robert J. Professor, University of Vermont College of Medicine, VT. Ettlinger, Carl F. President, Vermont Safety Research, VT. DOI: 10.1520/JAI101504 http://www.astm.org/DIGITAL_LIBRARY/JOURNALS/JAI/PAGES/1043.htm
  8. ^ How Fast Do Winter Sports Participants Travel on Alpine Slopes? Shealy, JE. Rochester Institute of Technology, Rochester, NY, USA. Ettlinger, CF. Vermont Safety Research, Underhill Center, VT, USA. Johnson, RJ. McClure Musculoskeletal Research Center, University of Vermont College of Medicine, Burlington, VT, USA. Journal of ASTM International Volume 2, Issue 7 (July/August 2005) "The average speed for helmet users of 45.8 km/h (28.4 mph) was significantly higher than those not using a helmet at 41.0 km/h (25.4 mph." DOI: 10.1520/JAI12092
  9. ^ [1] Seat belt savings: implications of European statistics. Isles JE, STG Division, Department of Transport, UK. Dated but not published April 1981. "The Isles Report"
  10. ^ Adams, Risk
  11. ^ Janssen, W. Seat belt wearing and driving behaviour: An instrumented-vehicle study. Accident Analysis and Prevention.1994 Apr; Vol 26(2): 249-2
  12. ^ Houston, David J., and Lilliard E. Richardson. "Risk Compensation or Risk Reduction? Seatbelts, State Laws, and Traffic Fatalities." Social Science Quarterly (Blackwell Publishing Limited) 88.4 (2007): 913-936. Business Source Complete. EBSCO. Web. 9 June 2011.
  13. ^ Jackson JSH, Blackman R (1994). A driving-simulator test of Wilde's risk homeostasis theory. Journal of Applied Psychology. 
  14. ^ Understanding children's injury-risk behavior: Wearing safety gear can lead to increased risk taking. Morrongiello BA, Walpole B, and Lasenby J. Accident Analysis & Prevention Volume 39, Issue 3, May 2007, Pages 618-623
  15. ^ Green, Edward C. (2009-03-29). "The Pope May Be Right". The Washington Post. http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/content/article/2009/03/27/AR2009032702825.html. 
  16. ^ "The pope was right about condoms, says Harvard HIV expert". Sunday Sequence. BBC Radio Ulster. 2009-03-29. http://www.bbc.co.uk/blogs/ni/2009/03/aids_expert_who_defended_the_p.html. 
  17. ^ Shelton, James D (2007-12-01). "Ten myths and one truth about generalised HIV epidemics". The Lancet 370 (9602): 1809–1811. http://www.thelancet.com/journals/lancet/article/PIIS0140-6736(07)61755-3/fulltext?_eventId=login.  "[...] condoms seem to foster disinhibition, in which people engage in risky sex either with condoms or with the intention of using condoms."

Other sources

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем сделать НИР

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Risk homeostasis — is a risk theory developed by Gerald J.S. Wilde, a professor emeritus of psychology at Queen s University, Kingston, Ontario, Canada. This theory is fleshed out in Wilde s book1.The theory of risk homeostasis states that an individual has an… …   Wikipedia

  • Risk premium — A risk premium is the minimum amount of money by which the expected return on a risky asset must exceed the known return on a risk free asset, in order to induce an individual to hold the risky asset rather than the risk free asset. Thus it is… …   Wikipedia

  • Compensation culture — describes a society in which it is acceptable for anyone who has suffered a personal injury to seek compensatory damages through litigation from someone connected with the injury. The term is especially used to describe the legal climate with… …   Wikipedia

  • Compensation methods — (Remuneration), Pricing models and business models used for the different types of internet marketing, including affiliate marketing, contextual advertising, search engine marketing (including vertical comparison shopping search engines and local …   Wikipedia

  • Compensation — • Denotes the price paid for human exertion or labour Catholic Encyclopedia. Kevin Knight. 2006. Compensation     Compensation     † …   Catholic encyclopedia

  • Risk Management Information Systems — (RMIS) are typically computerized systems that assist in consolidating property values, claims, policy, and exposure information and provide the tracking and management reporting capabilities to enable you to monitor and control your overall cost …   Wikipedia

  • Compensation Act 2006 — The Compensation Act 2006[1] Parliament of the United Kingdom Long title An Act to specify certain factors that may be taken into account by a court dete …   Wikipedia

  • risk — In insurance law, the danger or hazard of a loss of the property insured; the casualty contemplated in a contract of insurance; the degree of hazard; a specified contingency or peril; and, colloquially, the specific house, factory, ship, etc.,… …   Black's law dictionary

  • Risk Premium — The return in excess of the risk free rate of return that an investment is expected to yield. An asset s risk premium is a form of compensation for investors who tolerate the extra risk compared to that of a risk free asset in a given investment …   Investment dictionary

  • Risk management — For non business risks, see risk, and the disambiguation page risk analysis Example of risk management: A NASA model showing areas at high risk from impact for the International Space Station. Risk management is the identification, assessment,… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”