Labour power

Labour power

Labour power (in German: "Arbeitskraft", or labour force) is a crucial concept used by Karl Marx in his critique of capitalist political economy. He regarded labour power as the most important of the productive forces.

Under capitalism, according to Marx, the "productive powers of labour" appear as the "creative power of capital". Work becomes just work, workers become an abstract labour force, and the control over work becomes mainly a management prerogative.

Definition

Marx introduces the concept in chapter 6 of the first volume of "Capital" (generally known by its original German title, "Das Kapital)", as follows: :"By labour-power or capacity for labour is to be understood the aggregate of those mental and physical capabilities existing in a human being, which he exercises whenever he produces a use-value of any description." [http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch06.htm] He adds further on that::"Labour-power, however, becomes a reality only by its exercise; it sets itself in action only by working. But thereby a definite quantity of human muscle, nerve. brain, &c., is wasted, and these require to be restored.": [http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/ch06.htm]

A much shorter, to-the-point explanation of labour-power can be found in the introduction and second chapter of Marx's Wage Labour and Capital: [http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1847/wage-labour/index.htm]

Labour-power versus labour

According to Marx, there is a clear distinction between "labour" and "labour-power". "Labour" refers to the actual activity or effort of producing goods or services (or what Marx calls use-values). Neoclassical economists sometimes refer to this as "labour services." On the other hand, "labour-power" (or "labouring power") refers to a person's "ability" to work, his or her muscle-power, dexterity and brain-power. Marx took over this distinction from Hegel's "Philosophy of Right" and gave it a new significance.

In some ways, this concept is similar to that of "human capital". However most likely Marx himself would have considered the concept of human capital a reification, the purpose of which was to convince the worker that he was really a capitalist. The evidence for this interpretation is the following quote from "Capital Vol. 2":

The distinction Marx introduces between labour and labour-power was intended to solve a problem which David Ricardo failed to solve - the problem of explaining how surplus value could arise out of the exchange between capital and labour.

Labour power as commodity

Under capitalism, according to Marx, labour-power becomes a commodity – it is sold and bought on the market. A worker tries to sell his or her labour-power to an employer, in exchange for a wage or salary. If successful (the only alternative being unemployment), this exchange involves submitting to the authority of the capitalist for a specific period of time.

During that time, the worker does actual labour, producing goods and services. The capitalist can then sell these and realize a profit – what Marx called surplus value – since the wages paid to the workers are lower than the value of the goods or services they produce for the capitalist.

Value of labour Power

Labor power is a peculiar commodity, because it is an attribute of living persons, who own it themselves. Because they "own" it, they cannot "permanently" sell it to someone else; in that case, they would be a slave, and a slave does not own himself.

Labour power can become a marketable object, sold for a specific period, only if the owners are constituted in law as legal subjects who are free to sell it, and can enter into labour contracts. Once actualised and consumed through working, the capacity to work is exhausted, and must be replenished and restored.

In general, Marx argues that in capitalism the value of labour power (as distinct from fluctuating market prices for work effort) is equal to its "normal or average (re-)production cost", i.e. the established human needs which must be satisfied in order for the worker to turn up for work each day, fit to work. This involves goods and services representing a quantity of labour equal to necessary labour or the necessary product. It represents an average cost of living, an average living standard.

Included is both a "physical" component (the minimum physical requirements for a healthy worker) and a "moral-historical" component (the satisfaction of needs beyond the physical minimum which have become an established part of the lifestyle of the average worker). The value of labour power is thus an "historical norm", which is the outcome of a combination of factors: productivity; the supply and demand for labour; the assertion of human needs; the costs of acquiring skills; state laws stipulating minimum or maximum wages, the balance of power between social classes, etc.

Buying labour power usually becomes a "commercially" interesting proposition only if it can yield more value than it costs to buy, i.e. employing it yields a net positive return on capital invested. However, in Marx's theory, the value-creating function of labour power is not its "only" function; it also importantly "conserves" and "transfers" capital value. If labour is withdrawn from the workplace for any reason, typically the value of capital assets deteriorates; it takes a continual stream of work effort to maintain and preserve their value. When materials are used to make new products, part of the value of materials is also transferred to the new products. Consequently, labour power may be hired not "because it creates more value than it costs to buy", but simply because it "conserves the value of a capital asset" which, if this labour did not occur, would decline in value; or because it "transfers the value of a capital asset" from one owner to another. Marx regards such labour as "unproductive" in the sense that it creates no new value, but it may be absolutely essential and indispensable labour because without it a capital value would reduce or disappear.

Labour power and wages

Marx regards money-wages and salaries as the "price" of labour power (though workers can also be paid "in kind"). That price may contingently be higher or lower than the value of labour power, depending on market forces of supply and demand, on skill monopolies, legal rules, etc. Normally, unless government action prevents it, high unemployment will lower wages, and full employment will raise wages, in accordance with the laws of supply and demand. But wages can also be reduced through high price inflation and consumer taxes. Therefore a distinction must always be drawn between "nominal gross wages"' and "real wages" adjusted for tax and price inflation. The labour-costs of an employer are not the same as the real buying power a worker acquires through working.

There is typically a constant conflict over the level of wages between employers and employees, since employers seek to limit or reduce wage-costs, while workers seek to increase their wages, or at least maintain them. How the level of wages develops depends on the demand for labour, the level of unemployment, and the ability of workers and employers to organise and take action with regard to pay claims.

Marx regarded wages as the "external form" of the value of labour power. The compensation of workers in capitalist society could take all kinds of different forms, but there was always both a paid and unpaid component of labour performed. The "ideal" form of wages for capitalism, he argued, were "piece wages" because in that case the capitalist paid only for labour which directly created those outputs adding value to his capital. It was the most efficient form of exploitation of labour power.

Consumption of labour power

When labour power has been purchased and an employment contract signed, normally it is not yet paid for. First, labour power must be put to work in the production process. The employment contract is only a condition for uniting labour power with the means of production. From that point on, Marx argues, labour power at work is "transformed into capital", specifically variable capital which accomplishes the valorisation process.

Functioning as variable capital, living labour creates both use values and new value, conserves the value of constant capital assets, and transfers part of the value of materials and equipment used to the new products. The result aimed for is the valorisation of invested capital, i.e. other things being equal, the value of capital has increased through the activity of living labour.

At the end of the working day, labour power has been more or less consumed, and must be restored through rest, eating & drinking, and recreation.

*Note : medical estimates of the average holiday time necessary for workers to fully recuperate in a physiological and psychological sense from work stress during the year differ from country to country; but as an approximate gauge, three weeks continuous holiday is physiologically optimal for the average worker. ILO statistics show a wide range of average hours worked and average holidays for different countries; for example, Korean workers work far more hours per year, and Americans have fewer formal holidays than West Europeans. Several researchers have questioned however to what extent additional hours worked really increase the marginal productivity of labour; particularly in services, the work that gets done in five days could often also be done in four. The most difficult aspect to measure is the intensity of work, though some argue the incidence of work accidents are a reliable yardstick.

Reproduction of labour power

Marx himself argued that:

This understanding, however, only captures the sense in which the reproduction of labor power comes at no cost to capitalists, like the reproduction of ecological conditions, but unlike the reproduction of, say, machine bolts and plastic wrap. Elites and governments have always sought to actively intervene or mediate in the process of the reproduction of labour power, through family legislation, laws regulating sexual conduct, medical provisions, education policies, and housing policies. Such interventions always carry an economic cost, but that cost can be socialized or forced upon workers themselves, especially women. In these areas of civil society, there has been a constant battle between conservatives, social reformists and radicals.

Marxist-Feminists have argued that in reality, household (domestic) labour by housewives which forms, maintains and restores the capacity to work is a large "free gift" to the capitalist economy. Time use surveys show that formally unpaid and voluntary labour is a very large part of the total hours worked in a society. Markets depend on that unpaid labour to function at all.

Some feminists have therefore demanded that the government pay "wages for housework". This demand conflicts with the legal framework of the government in capitalist society, which usually assumes a financial responsibility only for the upkeep of "citizens" and "families" lacking other sources of income or subsistence.

Labour power and labour market flexibilisation

The commercial value of human labour power is strongly linked to the assertion of human needs by workers as citizens. It is not simply a question of supply and demand here, but of human needs which must be met. Therefore labour costs have "never" been simply an "economic" or "commercial" matter, but also a moral, cultural and political issue.

In turn, this has meant that governments have typically strongly regulated the sale of labour power with laws and rules for labour contracts. These laws and rules affect e.g. the minimum wage, wage bargaining, the operation of trade unions, the obligations of employers in respect of employees, hiring and firing procedures, labour taxes, and unemployment benefits.

This has led to repeated criticism from employers that labour markets are over-regulated, and that the costs and obligations of hiring labour weigh too heavily on employers. Moreover, it is argued that over-regulation prevents the free movement of labour to where it is really necessary. If labour markets were deregulated by removing excessive legal restrictions, it is argued that costs to business would be reduced and more labour could be hired, thereby increasing employment opportunities and economic growth.

However, trade union representatives often argue that the real effect of deregulation is to reduce wages and conditions for workers, with the effect of reducing market demand for products.In turn, the effect would be lower economic growth and a decline in living standards, with increased casualisation of labour and more "contingent labour".It is argued that, because the positions of employees and employers in the market are unequal, employees must be legally protected against undue exploitation.Otherwise employers will simply hire workers as and when it suits them, without regard for their needs as citizens.

Often the demand for "labour market flexibility" is combined with the demand for strong immigration controls, to block any movement of labour which would be only a burden for capital accumulation. The term "flexibility" is used because, while capital must be able to move freely around the globe, the movement of labour must be strictly controlled. If that control does not exist, it is argued, it could mean additional costs to employers and taxpayers. n

Criticism of the concept of labour power

There are five main kinds of criticism of Marx's concept.

*Critics have often argued that Marx's definition of labour-power, and how its value and price are regulated, is vague, incomplete, too general or imprecise; at any rate, that it permits different interpretations. In part, this criticism is anticipated by Marx, who acknowledged there was not just "one way" of valuing and compensating workers but many, although the "basic economic relationship" involved remained the same.

*It is argued by Ian Steedman that Marx's own concept of labour power was in truth very similar to that of David Ricardo and Adam Smith and therefore that Marx was not saying anything really new.

*Another sort of criticism is that whereas the concept of labour power may be perfectly valid, Marx misrepresents what happens when a worker enters into a labour contract with an employer (see Hodgson). It is argued for example that the worker does not sell his labour power but hires out (or leases out) his labour.

*Marx did not just disregard the many different forms in which workers could be remunerated (although he acknowledged their existence) but his provided no analysis of the labour market. Thus, while he might have provided an analysis of "capital", his analysis of "capitalism" is deficient because the labour market is a very important part of it.

*A recent criticism by Prof. Marcel van der Linden is as follows: :"Marx's thesis is based on two dubious assumptions, namely that labour needs to be offered for sale by the person who is the actual bearer and owner of such labour, and that the person who sells the labour sells nothing else. Why does this have to be the case? Why can labour not be sold by a party other than the bearer? What prevents the person who provides labour (his or her own or that of somebody else) from offering packages combining the labour with labour means? And why can a slave not perform wage labour for his master at the estate of some third party?" [http://info.interactivist.net/article.pl?sid=04/11/02/1744204&mode=nested&ti] .

This difficulty is anticipated in research conducted during the 1980s by Tom Brass, gathered together in his 1999 book. Buying and selling of human work effort can and has taken many more different forms than Marx acknowledges - especially in the area of services. A modern information society makes possible all kinds of new forms of hustling.

References

*Samuel Bowles & Herbert Gintis, "The Problem with Human Capital Theory--A Marxian Critique", "American Economic Review", vol. 65(2), pages 74-82, (1975) [http://ideas.repec.org/a/aea/aecrev/v65y1975i2p74-82.html]

*Tom Brass, "Towards a Comparative Political Economy of Unfree Labour: Case Studies and Debates." (Frank Cass, London, 1999).

*Tom Brass and Marcel Van Der Linden (eds.), "Free and Unfree Labour: The Debate Continues" (International and Comparative Social History, 5). New York: Peter Lang AG, 1997.

*Harry Braverman, "Labor and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century". New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974.

*"The Critical Lawyer's Handbook"m [http://www.nclg.org.uk/book1/2_10.htm]

*Ben Fine, "Labour Market Theory: A Constructive Reassessment". Routledge, London, 1998.

*Bonnie Fox, "Hidden in the Household: Women's Domestic Labour Under Capitalism", Women's Press, 1980.

*Ian Gough & L.Doyal, "A Theory of Human Need", Macmillan Press Ltd. 1991.

*Ian Gough, "Global Capital, Human Needs and Social Policies: Selected Essays 1994-99" London: Palgrave, 2000.

*Geofrey Hodgson, "Capitalism, Value and Exploitation" (Martin Robertson, Oxford, 1982).

*Makoto Itoh, "The Basic Theory of Capitalism: The Forms and Substance of the Capitalist Economy". Barnes & Noble, 1988.

*Kenneth Lapides, "Marx's Wage Theory in Historical Perspective: Its Origins, Development, and Interpretation". Westport: Praeger 1998.

*Ernest Mandel, The Formation of the Economic Thought of Karl Marx. Monthly Review Press, 1969.

*Karl Marx, "Das Kapital", Volume 1.

*Roman Rosdolsky, "The Making of Marx's "Capital". London: Pluto Press, 1977.

*Bob Rowthorn, "Marx's Theory of Wages", a chapter in Bob Rowthorn, "Capitalism, Conflict, and Inflation", Lawrence & Wishart, London.

*Ian Steedman, "Marx on Ricardo", in: Ian Bradley and Michael Howard (eds), Classical and Marxian Political Economy - Essays in honour of Ronald L. Meek". London: Macmillan, 1982.

*Peter Scholliers (ed.), "Real wages in 19th and 20th Century Europe; Historical and comparative perspectives". New York; Berg, 1989.

ee also

*human capital
*exploitation
*surplus value
*surplus labour
*surplus product
*variable capital
*productive forces
*Abstract labour and concrete labour
*Compensation of employees
*Reserve army of labour


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужна курсовая?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • labour-power — See labour theory of value …   Dictionary of sociology

  • Labour economics — seeks to understand the functioning of the market and dynamics for labour. Labour markets function through the interaction of workers and employers. Labour economics looks at the suppliers of labour services (workers), the demanders of labour… …   Wikipedia

  • labour-market — In a labour market, human effort (or labour power) is made into a commodity, which is bought and sold under terms which in law are deemed to constitute a contract. The purchase and sale of formally free labour developed extensively with… …   Dictionary of sociology

  • labour theory of value — The idea that labour is the ultimate source of all wealth a commonplace among the early political economists . Adam Smith , for example, argued that, in a market society in which workers owned their own means of production, the prices of goods… …   Dictionary of sociology

  • labour — In most sociological contexts this term is synonymous with wage labour . However, in Marxism attention is often drawn to the conflicting interests of ‘Labour’ and ‘Capital’. The former is here a reference to the proletariat , and alludes to the… …   Dictionary of sociology

  • Labour and Labour Legislation — • Labour is work done by mind or body either partly or wholly for the purpose of producing utilities Catholic Encyclopedia. Kevin Knight. 2006. Labour and Labour Legislation     Labour and Labour Legislation …   Catholic encyclopedia

  • Labour law — concerns the inequality of bargaining power between employers and workers. Labour law (also called labor law or employment law) is the body of laws, administrative rulings, and precedents which address the legal rights of, and restrictions on,… …   Wikipedia

  • Labour Unions (Moral Aspects) —     Labour Unions (Moral Aspects)     † Catholic Encyclopedia ► Labour Unions (Moral Aspects)     Since a labour union is a society, its moral aspects are determined by its constitution, its end, its results, and the means employed in pursuit of… …   Catholic encyclopedia

  • Labour Party (Norway) — Labour Party Arbeiderpartiet Leader Jens Stoltenberg Parliamentary leader …   Wikipedia

  • Labour Party (Netherlands) — Labour Party Partij van de Arbeid Leader Job Cohen Party Chairperson …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”