Rational expectations

Rational expectations

Rational expectations is an assumption used in many contemporary macroeconomic models, and also in other areas of contemporary economics and game theory and in other applications of rational choice theory.

Since most macroeconomic models today study decisions over many periods, the expectations of workers, consumers, and firms about future economic conditions are an essential part of the model. How to model these expectations has long been controversial, and it is well known that the macroeconomic predictions of the model may differ depending on the assumptions made about expectations (see Cobweb model). To assume rational expectations is to assume that agents' expectations are correct on average. In other words, although the future is not fully predictable, agents' expectations are assumed not to be systematically biased and use all relevant information in forming expectations of economic variables.

This way of modeling expectations was originally proposed by John F. Muth (1961) and later became influential when it was used by Robert E. Lucas Jr and others. Modeling expectations is crucial in theories like new classical macroeconomics, new Keynesian macroeconomics, and the efficient market hypothesis of contemporary finance, which study the dynamics of the economy over time. For example, negotiations between workers and firms will be influenced by the expected level of inflation, and the value of a share of stock is dependent on the expected future income from that stock.

Theory

Rational expectations theory defines this kind of expectations as being identical to the "best guess of the future" (the optimal forecast) that uses all available information. However, without further assumptions, this theory of expectations determination makes no predictions about human behavior and is empty. Thus, it is assumed that outcomes that are being forecast do not differ systematically from the market equilibrium results. As a result, rational expectations do not differ systematically or predictably from equilibrium results. That is, it assumes that people do not make systematic errors when predicting the future, and deviations from "perfect foresight" are only random. In an economic model, this is typically modelled by assuming that the expected value of a variable is equal to the value predicted by the model, plus a random error term representing the role of ignorance and mistakes.

For example, suppose that "P" is the equilibrium price in a simple market, determined by supply and demand. The theory of rational expectations says that the actual price will only deviate from the expectation if there is an 'information shock' caused by information unforeseeable at the time expectations were formed. In other words ex ante the actual price is equal to its rational expectation.:

::: "P" = "P*" + "e"

::: "E(P)" = "P*"

where P* is the rational expectation and "e" is the random error term, which has an expected value of zero, and is independent of "P*".

Rational expectations theories were developed in response to perceived flaws in theories based on adaptive expectations. Under adaptive expectations, expectations of the future value of an economic variable are based on past values. For example, people would be assumed to predict inflation by looking at inflation last year and in previous years. Under adaptive expectations, if the economy suffers from constantly rising inflation rates (perhaps due to government policies), people would be assumed to always underestimate inflation. This may be regarded as unrealistic - surely rational individuals would sooner or later realise the trend and take it into account in forming their expectations? Further, models of adaptive expectations never attain equilibrium, instead only moving toward it asymptotically.

The hypothesis of rational expectations addresses this criticism by assuming that individuals take all available information into account in forming expectations. Though expectations may turn out incorrect, they will not deviate systematically from the expected values.

The rational expectations hypothesis has been used to support some radical conclusions about economic policymaking. An example is the Policy Ineffectiveness Proposition developed by Thomas Sargent and Neil Wallace. If the Federal Reserve attempts to lower unemployment through expansionary monetary policy economic agents will anticipate the effects of the change of policy and raise their expectations of future inflation accordingly. This in turn will counteract the expansionary effect of the increased money supply. All that the government can do is raise the inflation rate, not employment. This is a distinctly New Classical outcome. During the 1970s rational expectations appeared to have made previous macroeconomic theory largely obsolete, which culminated with the Lucas critique. However, rational expectations theory has been widely adopted throughout modern macroeconomics as a modelling assumption thanks to the work of New Keynesians such as Stanley Fischer.

Rational expectations theory is the basis for the efficient market hypothesis (efficient market theory). If a security's price does not reflect all the information about it, then there exist "unexploited profit opportunities": someone can buy (or sell) the security to make a profit, thus driving the price toward equilibrium. In the strongest versions of these theories, where all profit opportunities "have been" exploited, all prices in financial markets are correct and reflect market fundamentals (such as future streams of profits and dividends). Each financial investment is as good as any other, while a security's price reflects all information about its intrinsic value.

Criticisms

The hypothesis is often criticised as an unrealistic model of how expectations are formed. First, truly rational expectations would take into account the fact that information about the future is "costly." The "optimal forecast" may be the best not because it is accurate but because it is too expensive to attain even close to accuracy. Followers of the Austrian School and John Maynard Keynes go further, pointing to the fundamental uncertainty about what will happen in the future. That is, the future "cannot" be predicted, so that "no" expectations can be truly "rational."Fact|date=January 2008

Further, the models of Muth and Lucas (and the strongest version of the efficient markets hypothesis) assume that at any specific time, a market or the economy has "only one" equilibrium (which was determined ahead of time), so that people form their expectations around this unique equilibrium.Fact|date=January 2008 Muth's math (sketched above) assumed that "P*" was unique. Lucas assumed that equilibrium corresponded to a unique "full employment" level (potential output) -- corresponding to a unique NAIRU or natural rate of unemployment. If there is more than one possible equilibrium at any time then the more interesting implications of the theory of rational expectations do not apply. In fact, expectations would determine the nature of the equilibrium attained, reversing the line of causation posited by rational expectations theorists.

A further problem relates to the application of the rational expectations hypothesis to aggregate behavior. It is well known that assumptions about individual behavior do not carry over to aggregate behavior (Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem). The same holds true for rationality assumptions: Even if all individuals have rational expectations, the representative household describing these behaviors may exhibit behavior that does not satisfy rationality assumptions (Janssen 1993). Hence the rational expectations hypothesis, as applied to the representative household, is unrelated to the presence or absence of rational expectations on the micro level and lacks, in this sense, a microeconomic foundation.

It can be argued that it is difficult to apply the standard efficient market hypothesis (efficient market theory) to understand the stock market bubble that ended in 2000 and collapsed thereafter. (Advocates of Rational Expectations may say that the problem of ascertaining all the pertinent effects of the stock-market crash is a great challenge.)

Sociologists tend to criticize the theory based on philosopher Karl Popper's criterion of falsifiability. They note that many economists, upon being confronted with empirical data that goes against the "rational" theory, can simply modify their theories without ever touching the basic thesis of rational expectation.Fact|date=January 2008 Furthermore, social scientists in general criticize the movement of this theory into other fields such as political science. In his book "Essence of Decision," political scientist Graham T. Allison specifically attacked the rational expectations theory.

Philosophers have made similar arguments, claiming that the entire "rational expectation" theory was originated by Thomas Hobbes.Fact|date=January 2008

Some economists now use the adaptive expectations model, but then complement it with ideas based on the rational expectations theory. For example, an anti-inflation campaign by the central bank is more effective if it is seen as "credible," "i.e.," if it convinces people that it will "stick to its guns." The bank can convince people to lower their inflationary expectations, which implies less of a feedback into the actual inflation rate. (An advocate of Rational Expectations would say, rather, that the pronouncements of central banks are facts that must be incorporated into one's forecast because central banks can act independently). Those studying financial markets similarly apply the efficient-markets hypothesis but keep the existence of exceptions in mind.

A specific field of economics, called behavioral economics, has emerged from those considerations, of which Daniel Kahneman (Nobel prize 2002) is one of the pioneers and main theorist.

See also

*Adaptive expectations
*Game theory
*Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

References

* Maarten C. W. Janssen (1993) "Microfoundations: A Critical Inquiry". Routledge.
* Hanish C. Lodhia (2005) "The Irrationality of Rational Expectations - An Exploration into Economic Fallacy". 1st Edition, Warwick University Press, UK.
* John F. Muth (1961) "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements" reprinted in "The new classical macroeconomics. Volume 1." (1992): 3-23 (International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, vol. 19. Aldershot, UK: Elgar.)
*Thomas J. Sargent (1987). "Rational expectations," "", v. 4, pp. 76-79.
* N.E. Savin (1987). "Rational expectations: econometric implications," "", v. 4, pp. 79-85.

External links

* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/RationalExpectations.html An article] by Thomas Sargent in the Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • rational expectations — racionalieji lūkesčiai statusas Aprobuotas sritis Ekonomika apibrėžtis Rinkos procesų ar ekonominių rodiklių lūkesčiai, grindžiami logika ir visa rinkos dalyviams prieinama informacija. atitikmenys: angl. rational expectations ryšiai: platesnis… …   Lithuanian dictionary (lietuvių žodynas)

  • Rational Expectations Theory — An economic idea that the people in the economy make choices based on their rational outlook, available information and past experiences. The theory suggests that the current expectations in the economy are equivalent to what the future state of… …   Investment dictionary

  • rational expectations theory — racionaliųjų lūkesčių teorija statusas Aprobuotas sritis Ekonomika apibrėžtis Teorija, grindžiama prielaida, kad rinkos dalyviai, numatydami rinkos procesus ar ekonominius rodiklius, vadovaujasi logika ir įvertina visą jiems prieinamą informaciją …   Lithuanian dictionary (lietuvių žodynas)

  • Rational expectations — The idea that people rationally anticipate the future and respond to what they see ahead. The New York Times Financial Glossary …   Financial and business terms

  • rational expectations — The idea that people rationally anticipate the future and respond today to what they see ahead. This concept was pioneered by Nobel Laureate, Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Bloomberg Financial Dictionary …   Financial and business terms

  • rational expectations — The theory, developed by the economist John Muth, that economic transactors make unbiased forecasts on the basis of all the information available. They thus do not make systematic forecasting errors …   Big dictionary of business and management

  • rational expectations — …   Useful english dictionary

  • rational expectations hypothesis — …   Useful english dictionary

  • Rational choice theory — This article is about a theory of economics. For Rational Choice Theory as applied to criminology, see Rational choice theory (criminology). Economics …   Wikipedia

  • rational expectationist — noun see rational expectations …   Useful english dictionary

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”