The commons

The commons

The commons is terminology referring to resources that are owned in common[1] or shared between or among communities populations. These resources are said to be "held in common" and can include everything from natural resources and common land to software.[2] The commons contains public property and private property, over which people have certain traditional rights. In some areas the process by which commonly held property is transformed into private property is termed enclosure.

Contents

Concepts

The commons were traditionally defined as the elements of the environment - forests, atmosphere, rivers, fisheries or grazing land - that are shared, used and enjoyed by all.

Today, the commons are also understood within a cultural sphere. These commons include literature, music, arts, design, film, video, television, radio, information, software and sites of heritage. The commons can also include public goods such as public space, public education, health and the infrastructure that allows our society to function (such as electricity or water delivery systems). There also exists the ‘life commons’, e.g. the human genome.

Peter Barnes describes commons as a set of assets that have two characteristics: they’re all gifts, and they’re all shared. A shared gift is one we receive as members of a community, as opposed to individually. Examples of such gifts include air, water, ecosystems, languages, music, holidays, money, law, mathematics, parks and the Internet.[3]

There are a number of important aspects that can be used to describe true commons. The first is that the commons cannot be commodified – and if they are – they cease to be commons. The second aspect is that unlike private property, the commons is inclusive rather than exclusive — its nature is to share ownership as widely, rather than as narrowly, as possible. The third aspect is that the assets in commons are meant to be preserved regardless of their return of capital. Just as we receive them as shared gifts, so we have a duty to pass them on to future generations in at least the same condition as we received them. If we can add to their value, so much the better, but at a minimum we must not degrade them, and we certainly have no right to destroy them.[3]

The Public commons is commonly referred to as a place in our world that has a public good that is free for people to view and enjoy and owned by everyone who wants to be a part of it. Something as simple as water and grass that you see in the park everyday is a public common. Most times people don’t even realize that when they’re in a park that it is free. However usually in these commons it is patrolled by other people in the area and if someone were to violate the commons in anyway by littering or dumping then it would be up to people in the area to control what happens to their own place.

Some people don’t tend to agree with Peter Barnes in saying that the commons is all owned by the people because things like public transportation, public education and health care aren’t always available to people. For each of these mentioned things each of them has a “care penalty” in which there is a certain fee or tax to use these things provided by the government. This type of common is provided by a certain infrastructure like the government but to have access to it there is taxes on families and health insurance premiums. Another highly used public common is the internet. The internet is something many people have access to as a resource and a scholarly tool but is also privatized as well. This type of common is a hybrid. To gain access to the internet a household needs an internet service provider that they have to pay in order to get online.

There are quite a few different ways to categorize a “common” but there are the public commons like parks, rivers, oceans, mountains and grasslands but there are also the privatized commons that the government provides and lastly the hybrid of the two where the service is free but also privatized by certain groups or individuals.

While use of the commons is generally unrestricted, there have to be certain rules in place to ensure that they are available for future generations. Overuse of the commons threatens their very existence. When considering the commons as an entity used by all, it is easy to see how there are claims that the atmosphere and skies are commons. In that case it is not a matter of what is being taken from the resources, but what is being put into those commons.

Economist Peter Barnes has proposed sky trust to fix this problem. This idea claims that the sky belongs to all the people, and the companies do not have a right to over pollute. It is a type of cap and dividend program. Ultimately the goal would be to make polluting excessively more expensive than cleaning what is being put back into the atmosphere.[4]

Recently technological commons have become more prevalent. The Linux operating system is an open source rival to Windows and Microsoft that allows its users to take and use source code from other creators and modify it themselves.[5] In fact, Wikipedia itself is an open resource, and is an integral part of the information commons. Its users can update and add to any article. There are certain rules associated with these changes and its use, just like any other commons, but for the most part anyone can access it freely.[6]

In some ways, the information commons is required and actually helps protect the community. It is actually required that companies that pollute release information about what they are doing. The Corporate Toxics Information Project[7] and information like the Toxic 100, a list of the top 100 polluters,[8] helps people know what these large corporations are doing to the environment. Having the information open to all, as part of a common network helps ensure the safety and knowledge of anyone who wishes to access it.

Environmental examples

Mongolian grassland management

Based on a research project by the Environmental and Cultural Conservation in Inner Asia (ECCIA) from 1992 to 1995, satellite images were used to compare the amount of land degradation due to livestock grazing in the regions of Mongolia, Russia, and China[9]. In Mongolia, where shepherds were permitted to move collectively between seasonal grazing pastures, degradation remained relatively low at approximately 9%. Comparatively that of Russia and China, which implemented state-owned pastures involving immobile settlements and in some cases privatization by household, was much higher at around 75% and 33% respectively[10]. A collaborative effort on the part of Mongolians proved much more efficient in preserving grazing land.

Lobster fishery of Maine

Widespread success of the Maine lobster industry is often attributed to the willingness of Maine’s lobstermen to uphold and support lobster conservation rules. These rules include harbor territories not recognized by the state, informal trap limits, and laws imposed by the state of Maine (which are largely influenced by lobbying from lobster industry itself)[11]. Essentially, the lobstermen collaborate without much government intervention to sustain their common-pool resource.

Community forests in Nepal

Implemented in late 1980s, Nepal chose to decentralize government control over forests. Community forest programs work by giving local areas a financial stake in nearby woodlands, and therefore increasing the incentive to protect them from overuse. These local institutions regulate harvesting and selling of timber and land, and must use any profit towards community development and preservation of the forests. In twenty years, locals have noticed visible improvements in the number of trees.[12]

Acequia irrigation systems of New Mexico

Acequia is a method of collective responsibility and management for irrigation systems in desert areas. In New Mexico, a community-run organization known as Acequia Associations supervises water in terms of diversion, distribution, utilization, and recycling, in order to reinforce agricultural traditions and preserve water as a common resource for future generations.[13]

Historical movements

Contemporary movements

Key theorists

See also

References

  1. ^ Reclaiming the Commons, David Bollier, Boston Review, 2003
  2. ^ 'The Commons', Free Software Magazine
  3. ^ a b Barnes, Peter (2006). Capitalism 3.0: A Guide to Reclaiming the Commons. Berrett-Koehler Publishers. ISBN 978-1576753613. 
  4. ^ Barnes, Peter (2000). Pie in the Sky. Washington D.C: Corporation for Enterprise Development. p. 1. ISBN 1-883187-32-X. 
  5. ^ Kranich, Nancy. "The Information Commons". The Free Expresison Policy Project. NYU School of LAw. http://www.fepproject.org/policyreports/InformationCommons.pdf. Retrieved 10 May 2011. 
  6. ^ "Wikipedia:Introduction". Wikimedia. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:Introduction. 
  7. ^ "Corporate Toxics Information Project". Political Economy Research Institute. PERI-Umass. http://www.peri.umass.edu/Corporate-Toxics.298.0.html. 
  8. ^ Ash, Michael. "Justice in the Air". PERI. PERI- Umass. http://www.peri.umass.edu/fileadmin/pdf/dpe/ctip/justice_in_the_air.pdf. 
  9. ^ Sneath, David. "State Policy and Pasture Degradation in Inner Asia". Science Magazine. http://www.sciencemag.org/content/281/5380/1147.full?ijkey=2a465918ef9b55416bf136bee66c9175ccef1bdb&keytype2=tf_ipsecsha. Retrieved 11 May 2011. 
  10. ^ Ostrom, Elinor. "Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges". Science Magazine. http://www.sciencemag.org/content/284/5412/278.full#ref-8. Retrieved 11 May 2011. 
  11. ^ Acheson, James (2004). Capturing the Commons: Devising Institutions to Manage the Maine Lobster. University Press of New England. http://books.google.com/books?id=u23TkAVptOYC&printsec=frontcover&dq=james+acheson+lobster&hl=en&ei=oRrKTcKkAuK-0AGj2szmBw&sa=X&oi=book_result&ct=result&resnum=2&ved=0CDYQ6AEwAQ#v=onepage&q&f=false. 
  12. ^ Mehta, Trupti Parekh. "Community Forestry in India and Nepal". PERC Reports. 
  13. ^ Davidson-Harden, Adam. "Local Control and Management of Our Water Commons: Stories of Rising to the Challenge". www.ourwatercommons.org. http://ourwatercommons.org/sites/default/files/local-control-management-water-commons.pdf. Retrieved 11 May 2011. 

Further reading

  • Silvia Federici, Caliban and the Witch: Women, the Body and Primitive Accumulation (Brooklyn: Autonomedia, 2004)
  • Peter Linebaugh, The Magna Carta Manifesto: Liberties and Commons for All (University of California Press, 2008)
  • Peter Linebaugh and Marcus Rediker, The Many-Headed Hydra: Sailors, Slaves, Commoners, and the Hidden History of the Revolutionary Atlantic (Boston: Beacon Press, 2000)
  • Hugo P. Leaming, Hidden Americans: Maroons of Virginia and the Carolinas (Routledge, 1995)
  • Marcus Nevitt, Women and the Pamphlet Culture of Revolutionary England, 1640—1660 (Ashgate Publishing, 2006)
  • Raj Patel, The Value of Nothing (Portobello Books, 2010)
  • Retort, Afflicted Powers: Capital and Spectacle in a New Age of War (Verso, 2005) Geoff Kennedy, Diggers, Levellers, and Agrarian Capitalism: Radical Political Thought in 17th Century England (Lexington Books, 2008)
  • Christopher Hill, Winstanley ‘The Law of Freedom’ and other Writings (Cambridge University Press, 2006)
  • Christopher Hill, The World Turned Upside Down: Radical Ideas During the English Revolution (Penguin, 1984)
  • Neil Harvey, The Chiapas Rebellion: The Struggle for Land and Democracy (Duke University Press, 1998)
  • Douglas Lummis, Radical Democracy (Cornell University Press 1997)
  • Richard Price editor, Maroon Societies: Rebel Slave Communities in the Americas (The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1979)
  • Kenneth Rexroth, Communalism: From Its Origins to the Twentieth Century (Seabury Press, 1974)
  • Pauline Gregg, Free-Born John: A Biography of John Lilburne (Phoenix Press, 2001)
  • J.M. Neeson, Commoners: Common Right, Enclosure and Social Change in England, 1700—1820 (Cambridge University Press, 1996)
  • John Hanson Mitchel, Trespassing: An Inquiry into the Private Ownership of Land (Perseus Books, 1998)
  • Pierre-Joseph Proudhon, What is Property (Cambridge University Press, 1994)
  • Charles Fourier, The Theory of the Four Movements(Cambridge University Press, 1996)

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать реферат

Look at other dictionaries:

  • (The) Commons —    Messuage called The Commons in parish of St. James Garlickhithe in the tenure of divers priests granted by Edward VI. to Nicholas Spakeman (Strype, ed. 1720, I. iii. 12).    Not further identified …   Dictionary of London

  • The Commons at Federal Way — Infobox shopping mall shopping mall name = The Commons at Federal Way image width = caption = location = address = coordinates = opening date = 1975 closing date = developer = manager = owner = number of stores = 90+ number of anchors = 4 floor… …   Wikipedia

  • Music by the Commons — The logo of Music by the Commons Music by the Commons is an Early music society which organises regular concerts in Wimbledon, South West London, England. It mainly features music written before 1830.[1] The music is performed on auth …   Wikipedia

  • Tragedy of the commons — Cows on Selsley Common. The tragedy of the commons is one way of accounting for overexploitation. The tragedy of the commons is a dilemma arising from the situation in which multiple individuals, acting independently and rationally consulting… …   Wikipedia

  • Wikipedia:Moving files to the Commons — For other uses, see Wikipedia:WikiProject Images and Media/Commons. Shortcuts: WP:MTC WP:MITC WP:TOCOMMONS WP:TRANSFER Many files have been uploaded to Wikipedia. A long term project under way is to move …   Wikipedia

  • On the Commons — (formerly Tomales Bay Institute) is a network of citizens and organizations, based in Minneapolis, Minnesota in the United States, working to highlight the importance of the commons in the modern world. On the Commons promotes commons based… …   Wikipedia

  • Tragedy Of The Commons — An economic problem in which every individual tries to reap the greatest benefit from a given resource. As the demand for the resource overwhelms the supply, every individual who consumes an additional unit directly harms others who can no longer …   Investment dictionary

  • tragedy of the commons — the decline or loss of a common property natural resource through continued exploitation after the maximum sustainable yield has been reached. Unhappily true of many fisheries where no one owns them and so no one has a vested interest in… …   Dictionary of ichthyology

  • Commons-based peer production — is a term coined by Harvard Law School professor Yochai Benkler to describe a new model of socio economic production in which the creative energy of large numbers of people is coordinated (usually with the aid of the Internet) into large,… …   Wikipedia

  • Commons Act 2006 — The Commons Act 2006[1] Parliament of the United Kingdom Long title An Act to make provision about common land and town or village g …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”